Derivation of Black-Scholes Model
Model 1
At time point , let’s say the price of units of the underlying asset , and assume that undergoes Geometric Brownian Motion. That is, for Standard Brownian Motion , drift , and diffusion , is the solution to the following Stochastic Differential Equation. When a risk-free rate is given, the price of units of the derivative at time follows the following [Partial Differential Equation](../../categories/Partial Differential Equations).
Variables
- : Derivatives refer to financial instruments such as futures and options.
- : Underlying Assets are the commodities traded in derivatives, such as currency, bonds, and stocks.
Parameters
- : Represents the interest rate of Risk-free Assets. A typical example of a risk-free asset is a deposit.
- : Represents the market’s Volatility.
Explanation
Contrary to common misconceptions about derivatives, futures and options were created as means of hedging against uncertain futures. It was a way to reduce risk by paying a certain premium, even if it cost a bit. The problem was the lack of an appropriate method to price them, and traders traded derivatives based on experience. The Black-Scholes model is an equation that made it possible to mathematically explain the price of such derivatives.
Commonly, the contributors to the Black-Scholes model (1973) are cited as Fischer Black, Myron Scholes, and Robert K. Merton, who introduced the ‘hedge-based derivation’ in this post. Unfortunately, Black passed away in 1995, and Scholes and Merton were awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1997. After the discovery of the Black-Scholes-Merton equation, the options market developed dazzlingly, and a new sub-discipline called financial engineering emerged in academia.
The Comedy of Black
According to Wikipedia2, Black frequently changed majors during his PhD studies and had trouble settling down in one field. He switched from physics to mathematics, to computer science, and to artificial intelligence, but eventually made a significant contribution in economics.
Although no reliable reference was found, it is said that Black, during his physics major, realized he couldn’t survive among the surrounding geniuses and became a pioneer in economics/finance, where there were no pioneers actively using mathematics, thus making a name for himself in a wasteland without science monsters.
The Tragedy of Scholes
According to Namuwiki3, Scholes caused a sensation at the 1997 Nobel Economics Prize press conference by saying he would invest the prize money in stocks. The hedge fund Scholes was managing went bankrupt in 1998 due to overconfidence and excessive leverage, following Russia’s default. After the crisis, Scholes managed to return profits to investors and continued as a fund manager until retiring just before the subprime mortgage crisis erupted.
Assumptions
Before delving into the derivation, let’s check some assumptions.
Factors such as commissions, taxes, and dividends are not considered
Think of it as not considering resistance, temperature, or atmospheric pressure in a physics model, which are not the focus of the study. Additionally, it’s assumed that the trend and are simply constants.
Derivatives depend on the underlying assets and timing
If the price of a derivative is independent of the underlying asset, there’s no need to use the terms ‘derivative’ and ‘underlying’. It’s reasonable for the price of a derivative to change as the price of the underlying asset changes. If it doesn’t change over time (if it’s constant), then there’s no point in pondering the price of a derivative. Thus, it’s assumed that is a function of at least two factors and , even if we can’t specify the exact form.
The underlying asset undergoes Geometric Brownian Motion
The primary application of Geometric Brownian Motion GBM is to explain the price fluctuations of underlying assets like stock prices. It assumes that the change in asset prices is proportional to the asset’s price, and that the price cannot become negative unless the asset is delisted, among other favorable assumptions.
Let’s assume the price of some stock follows GBM. The return, defined as taking the log of dividing the closing price on day by the closing price on day , aligns with our intuition that the return should be positive if the price increases and negative if it decreases, regardless of the stock’s size. As explained in the “Log-normal Distribution” section, this return follows a normal distribution, focusing on the essence of growth and decay rather than simple fluctuations.
Risk-free assets grow according to Malthusian growth
The Malthusian growth model is the simplest model describing the growth of a population without any limitations or interventions and can be used as an assumption to explain the proliferation of risk-free assets in economics/finance. The risk-free rate is assumed to be a constant , and the financial income is proportional to the size of asset , so it can be expressed by the following [Ordinary Differential Equation](../../categories/Ordinary Differential Equations).
Arbitrage-free pricing: There’s no value difference between portfolios
- A mathematical explanation of the portfolio will be further detailed in this proof.
The assumption of arbitrage-free pricing means that all portfolios we consider are balanced at the same value. For instance, if the value of portfolio is higher than , a rational market participant would increase the proportion of the more valuable to make a profit, so there’s no reason to consider . Therefore, it’s assumed that the portfolios we consider are already in a state where no further profits can be made through such arbitrage.
Frictionless market: There are no restrictions on division and short selling
Anyone who has traded stocks knows that there are minimum bidding units, so you can’t trade exactly the amount you want, and there are restrictions on short selling in the Korean stock market, where borrowed short selling (borrowing stocks) is the principle. Being able to divide trading units as desired and short sell without any restrictions can be considered as having no friction opposing actions.
Derivation
Part 1. Portfolio Composition
Let’s assume we can only hold three types of assets:
- Underlying Asset: Let’s say we hold units.
- Derivative: Let’s say we hold units.
- Risk-free Asset: An asset that is neither an underlying asset nor a derivative, which can be considered as cash.
If we denote the value of all assets we hold at time as , and if was the price of units of the underlying asset and was the price of units of the derivative, it can be represented as follows. Composing a portfolio means adjusting the amounts of and , in other words, strategizing on how to invest. Assuming that the trading volume generated by such portfolio composition significantly affects the market is irrational, so the prices of the underlying asset and derivative are independent of the choices of and . In other words, the mathematical discussions that follow do not change regardless of how and are determined.
It’s important to note that is not the sum of the total assets. It’s easier to understand if you think of it as looking only at the stock balance, not the cash account. Let’s think about what portfolios could be:
- Savings : Clear the stock account and put everything into savings to receive interest. It might seem trivial to a scholar who knows nothing but mathematics, but it’s a legitimate strategy for dealing with market crashes or recessions.
- Individual Investor : Individuals should not touch derivatives. Most individual investors in countries where short selling is banned have this type of portfolio. For example, if is the stock price of Samsung Electronics, this portfolio is my friend ‘Kim Soo-hyung’s account holding shares of Samsung Electronics.
- Hedge : Consider buying a call option and short selling the underlying asset . If the price of the underlying asset increases significantly on the expiration date of the option, the call option will bring in a large profit, and if the price of the underlying asset falls, profit will have been made from the short sale early on.
The options mentioned in the explanation of hedging and to be covered later are European Options, which are usually known as ‘options that can only be exercised on the expiration date’. American Options can be exercised at any time before maturity, but that’s not our concern here, so don’t be intimidated by the terms European and American.
We will derive the Black-Scholes equation from the last example, a portfolio that hedges a derivative with a spot short sale Since it’s perfectly hedged, this portfolio is a risk-free asset, and the increment over time is Here, since is assumed to follow Geometric Brownian Motion, substituting for yields Considering the assumption of arbitrage-free pricing, the increment of this portfolio should be the same as that of a risk-free asset portfolio. If we assume there’s a price difference between the portfolios, profit could be made by liquidating one portfolio and investing in the other. Since we assumed risk-free assets grow according to Malthusian growth, the risk-free rate can be expressed by the following [Ordinary Differential Equation](../../categories/Ordinary Differential Equations). Organizing these, we get thus, is obtained. Now, let’s use Itô calculus to find .
Part 2. Itô Calculus
Itô’s Lemma: Given an Itô Process , for function , if we set , then is also an Itô Process, and the following holds.
In Geometric Brownian Motion, distributing according to the distributive law gives and, from Itô’s Lemma, since and , we obtain Substituting this into for gives Since the portfolio’s value was defined as , substituting this yields Rearranging the equation for , we obtain the desired equation.
■
Byung-Seon Choi. (2012). Various Derivations of the Black-Scholes Formula ↩︎